Cognitive function, numeracy and retirement saving trajectories
. Author manuscript; available in PMC: 2012 Nov 1.
Abstract
This paper examines the extent to which cognitive abilities relate to differences in trajectories for key economic outcomes as individuals move towards and through their retirement. We look at whether differences in baseline numeracy (measured in the English Longitudinal Study of Ageing in 2002) and broader cognitive ability predict the subsequent trajectories of outcomes such as wealth, retirement income and key dimensions of retirement expectations. Those with lower numeracy are shown to have different wealth trajectories both pre- and post-retirement than their more numerate counterparts, but the distributions of retirement expectations and net replacement rates are similar across numeracy groups.
Keywords: Numerical ability, Pensions, Retirement saving
The effects of cognitive ability on economic behaviour have become a topic of considerable research interest and policy concern. A subset of the resultant literature has looked at financial outcomes over the life course and examined the extent to which cognitive ability, numeracy and financial literacy are associated with financial saving, portfolio composition and asset accumulation as individuals age. The latter two of these dimensions – numeracy and financial literacy – have in particular become of widespread policy interest in the debate around retirement and pension policy in countries such as the United Kingdom where the extent of individual provision and hence individual choice in retirement saving institutions has been increasing substantially in recent years.
In this paper we look at the relationship between numeracy and various outcomes associated with wealth and well-being in retirement using the English Longitudinal Study of Aging (ELSA). Using an early cross-sectional wave of the same data, previous research has showed strong correlations between an individual’s level of numerical ability and their level of wealth, their level of financial knowledge and the composition of their asset portfolios (Banks and Oldfield, 2007). This correlation remains after conditioning on education and other dimensions of cognitive ability. Similar results are obtained in the United States in a recent analysis by Smith et al. (2010). The current paper builds on these analyses and has two aims. The first is to use changes in wealth between 2002 and 2006 to see whether saving and wealth accumulation trajectories vary across groups with different numerical ability. In this we focus in particular on the years immediately prior to retirement and the years immediately following it. The second aim of our paper is to assess whether there is any evidence that the correlations between numerical ability and wealth previously documented and those between numerical ability and saving that we document here are translated into differences in outcomes in retirement that might be thought to be more fundamental to welfare. These include income and consumption replacement rates, the degree to which prior expectations of the future are fulfilled, changes in subjective measures of well-being and the extent to which concerns about having enough resources to meet needs become more or less acute as individuals retire.
While our focus is on numeracy we take care to control for other dimensions of cognitive abilities – in this case, literacy, memory and executive function – as well as education and levels of accumulated wealth. This is in an attempt to control for the possibility that numeracy is simply acting as a marker of unobserved earnings capacity that is then manifesting itself in different retirement outcomes and saving trajectories. To the extent that earnings capacity and productivity is driven by general cognitive skills rather than numeracy alone then our measures of other cognitive abilities may be argued to capture this correlation.
Our results complement and extend those presented in Banks and Oldfield (2007) on the correlations between numerical ability and behaviour. We find evidence for a more pronounced ‘hump shape’ in private financial wealth amongst the more numerate. That is, in the years leading up to retirement those who are more numerate accumulate financial assets at a faster rate than those who are less numerate and that they decumulate it at a faster pace after retirement. However, in spite of the fact the different levels of numeracy are correlated with quite substantial differences in wealth and saving, we find little evidence that this it matters for the more fundamental outcomes listed above. We discuss some potential reasons for this finding below.
The paper proceeds as follows. In the next Section we review some of the literature on the interaction between cognitive ability and economic outcomes and discuss briefly the theoretical background that motivates our empirical analysis. Section 2 gives details of the data used for our analysis. We discuss in particular the cognitive data and the construction of the cognitive measures we use since these are somewhat new. Section 3 focuses on the link between numerical ability and life-cycle trajectories for financial wealth around the time of retirement. In Section 4 we move to look at a set of broader measures related to life-cycle smoothing, more specifically, changes in income and consumption on retirement, expectations of future employment and financial security, and measures of subjective well-being. Finally, Section 5 concludes and offers some thoughts on future research possibilities.
1. Theoretical Background
There are a number of reasons why we might expect differences in life-cycle wealth trajectories and retirement outcomes according to an individual’s numerical ability and cognitive function. Within the cognitive psychology literature there seems to be a wide acceptance that higher ability individuals are more patient (see for example: Parker and Fischhoff, 2005; Bettinger and Slonim, 2005; Kirby et al, 2005). Additionally, while it is less widely studied, evidence on the relationship between risk aversion and cognitive ability suggests that higher ability individuals are in fact less risk averse than those of lower ability (e.g. Frederick, 2005; Benjamin et al., 2006). In addition to confirming these findings Burks et al. (2009) report evidence that individuals with higher cognitive skills are more cooperative in a strategic setting. They conjecture that there is a causal factor underlying these correlations, namely that cognitive skills have a positive effect on the precision with which complex and/or future options are perceived. Finally, empirical evidence suggests that levels of self-control vary substantially within the population and are affected by cognitive capacity (Shiv and Fedorikhin, 1999) and economists are devoting increasing attention to theories of how dynamic inconsistencies, self-control and temptation might impact on intertemporal behaviours (e.g. Ainslie, 2001; Laibson, 1997; Gul and Pesendorfer, 2004).1
Many of these results have been established within laboratory experiments, with some recent studies also using cognitive load manipulation in the experimental design (essentially distracting subjects whilst they are taking their choices) in order to exploit within-subject variation in “ability” in identifying the effects of interest.2 Consideration of the issue of the extent of cognitive resources employed in decision-making, however, reveals the shortcomings of such empirical evidence for policy purposes since the time, effort and information deployed in making savings decisions in “real life” situations is most likely also a choice variable. In contrast, such factors are strictly controlled in a laboratory experiment. As an example, individuals with lower cognitive abilities may spend more (or less) time on their saving and pensions decisions than those with higher ability, or be more likely to use various forms of advice or information in their saving and investment decisions.3
Conversely, higher ability (and, particularly, more numerate) individuals may be more able to process information and make complex “optimal” decisions in a less costly manner. A series of studies has explored how the ability to understand and transform probabilities relates to performance on judgement and decision tasks. Peters et al. (2005) summarise their evidence as showing that more numerate individuals were “more likely to retrieve and use appropriate numerical principles, thus making themselves less susceptible to framing effects”4. They also note that these more numerate individuals “tended to draw different (generally stronger or more precise) affective meaning from numbers and numerical comparisons, and their affective responses were more precise”. Numerical ability appears to matter to complex judgements and decisions in important ways, although the extent to which this evidence is relevant here will depend the extent to which individuals of different numeracy levels differ in their investment planning behaviour or advice-seeking behaviour.
Given the complexity of saving and portfolio choices facing individuals in modern financial markets and the relatively specific nature of the evidence from cognitive psychology, there is considerable merit in looking at economic data on the distribution of saving and wealth outcomes across cognitive abilities, even bearing in mind the empirical difficulties discussed above. Data combining information on economic outcomes and cognitive abilities are now becoming available with which such hypotheses can be investigated. Benjamin et al. (2006) use the US National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY) to look at the relationship between cognitive ability and a very crude measure of asset accumulation and find low cognitive function to be associated with low levels of asset accumulation and financial market participation. More relevant to our study, Banks and Oldfield (2007) show significant correlations between the level of financial wealth and both a broad measure of cognitive functioning and a narrow measure of numerical ability based on performance in a series of simple calculations. These associations hold when both measures are used simultaneously in a model that also includes measures of education as well as gender and age dummies. Of course, higher cognitive abilities typically result in higher earnings, but what is striking is the role of numeracy over and above other dimensions of cognitive abilities. To the extent that human capital is sufficiently controlled for by general measures of cognitive functioning and memory in these estimates, the role of numeracy may be thought to be indicating a separate mechanism relating to preferences for saving out of lifetime income. Finally, when it comes to portfolio decisions, cognitive ability and numeracy were both associated with a higher likelihood of holding stocks and of having a private pension, even when controlling for the level of financial wealth in addition to the factors mentioned above.5
What might the above mean for the intertemporal trajectories of economic variables such as consumption, wealth and retirement incomes? With more numerate individuals being more patient a standard life-cycle model would suggest, other things being equal, smoother consumption trajectories as individuals pass from employment to retirement. That is to say, whilst all individuals will smooth (expected) discounted marginal utilities, the consequences for consumption expenditures will be more smoothness for more numerate individuals. This picture is complicated, however, by the fact that social institutions (such as state provision in retirement and other welfare payments) are likely to have differing impact on those with different numerical abilities. We show below, for example, that individuals with lower numeracy can expect to have a greater fraction of their pre-retirement incomes replaced by the state when they retire.6
In the absence of a fully specified structural dynamic model, or at least a comprehensive evaluation of the extent to which the primitives of preferences and constraints (risk aversion, discount rate, optimisation costs etc.) and the effect of social institutions and informal insurance mechanisms vary over groups with different numeracy, it is not clear a priori how the life-cycle path of consumption and other indicators of economic welfare in retirement would be predicted to vary by numeracy group. Our research aims to identify some of the stylised empirical facts that could inform, and/or subsequently be explained by, future research along these more structural lines.
2. Data
Our analysis uses the first three waves of the English Longitudinal Study of Ageing (ELSA) which is a large sample of those aged over 50 years old. The study contains comprehensive data on financial circumstances (including savings and pension arrangements) as well as detailed information on health and socioeconomic factors (see Marmot et al. 2003 for more details and a further description of the ELSA data). Data are collected every two years with a Computer Aided Personal Interview (CAPI) questionnaire in a face to face visit from a trained interviewer. A self-completion booklet is also left behind for completion by each respondent and subsequently returned by post. Finally, biological samples and anthropometric data are collected every four years with a nurse visit. Data from the study have already been used to look at a diverse set of issues ranging from pension and retirement saving outcomes (Banks et al., 2005) to physical health and functioning (see for example: Banks et al. 2006; Melzer et al., 2005) and quality of life (Netuveli et al., 2006). These papers demonstrate the advantages of collecting data on multiple dimensions of circumstances and functioning in later life.
ELSA is designed to be a representative sample of those aged over 50 and living in the private household sector England on 28 February 2002. 11,392 such individuals were interviewed at wave 1 in 2002. In 2004 and 2006, 9,324 and 7,976 respectively of these were interviewed. If an individual is in the sample, so too is their partner, and both adults are interviewed as part of the survey.7 The set of people interviewed includes partners aged under 50 or new partners that join households between waves but such individuals are not sample members in their own right. Partners under the age of 50 are excluded from the sub-sample that we use.
One reason for the decline in sample sizes across waves is mortality, since our sample comprises a large fraction of older individuals. It is clear from the numbers given above, however, that there was substantial attrition in the sample between 2002 and 2006. Banks et al. (2010) analyse the scale and nature of attrition and non-response in ELSA. Whilst very few individual level characteristics predict subsequent attrition, one relevant conclusion in the present context is their finding that attrition is related to the cognitive ability of respondents. Individuals with a greater level of cognitive ability are less likely to drop out of the sample than individuals with lesser levels. To mitigate the extent to which our results will have been affected by such attrition, all our results use a balanced panel of only those who respond in all three waves. This will ensure that differences in trajectories observed between groups are not due to differential attrition, at the expense of the potential representativeness of the sample in the baseline wave. Our results will still generalise to the broader population to the extent that the relationship between our outcomes of interest (e.g. longitudinal wealth trajectories, accuracy of expectations etc.) and cognitive ability do not vary systematically, conditional on the control variables in our models, between those who drop out of the sample and those who remain.
The ‘core’ ELSA questionnaire is delivered in each wave and collects details of all savings, investments and debts held by sample members as well as full details of their pension arrangements, housing wealth and various indicators of financial expectations. For the purposes of this paper we use measures of financial wealth and income defined at the benefit unit level (i.e. either a couple or single adult plus any dependent children they have).
The ELSA core questionnaire also includes a module of questions designed to measure cognitive ability and it is these measures that we will focus on in this paper. These cognitive measures are designed to partition cognitive functioning into two broad domains, each with subcomponents for which blocks of measures have been designed. The first domain relates to memory, with components comprising retrospective memory (recalling things from the past) and prospective memory (remembering to remember things in the future). The second domain, perhaps more relevant for our analysis, relates to executive functioning. In this domain the ELSA instrument comprises specific tasks (relating to verbal fluency, attention, visual search and mental speed) and a set of questions to identify numerical ability and literacy. With respect to the latter, numerical ability questions were delivered in 2002 and a short literacy module was delivered in 2004.8 Steel et al. (2003) describe all the tests (excluding literacy) in more detail and derive a global cognitive index and show that this index covaries with factors in the expected ways. For example global cognitive function is lower in older age groups and higher for individuals with more education or better health.
2.1 Measurements of numeracy and literacy
As numeracy measures are a key element of what follows, we briefly outline the key measures here although the measure used is identical to that described in more detail in Banks and Oldfield (2007). In addition, subsequent to that paper, data on literacy has been collected for ELSA respondents so we will briefly discuss the correlation with numeracy and include literacy in much of our subsequent analysis.
The 2002 ELSA questionnaire asked respondents up to five basic questions involving successively more complex numerical calculations.9 The six possible questions are presented in Appendix 1. Answers to all questions are entirely unprompted (i.e. respondents are not given a menu of possible answers to choose from). Each respondent initially receives questions 2, 3 and 4. If all of these are answered incorrectly the respondent receives question 1 and that is the end of their numeracy module. Otherwise the respondent receives question 5. If the respondent reports a correct answer to any (or all) of questions 3, 4 and 5, they receive the final and most difficult question q6 that requires an understanding of compound interest. Since more able individuals receive more questions in this design the number of questions answered correctly is a straightforward measure of numerical ability that can be derived simply from this module. This is the measure summarised by Steel et al. (2003) in their initial descriptive analysis of the ELSA data.
The numerical ability measure we derive from the ELSA data is instead designed to place individuals into one of four groups according to their broad numerical ability. This has the advantage of allowing us to choose groups that have some prevalence in the population since a simple counting of correct answers does not take into account the relative difficulty of the questions and furthermore may lead to some clusters where there are many observations, with relatively few individuals at the extremes. Hence for our analysis we choose to define numerical ability in four broad groups according to which of the questions were correctly answered. This coding is indicated in Appendix 1.10
Our measure of numeracy is a very specific measure, focusing on an individual’s abilities to carry out simple numerical calculations accurately. We do not have access to broader measures of financial literacy such as those used by Lusardi and Mitchell (2007) that capture other dimensions such as knowledge of financial products, knowledge of different types of risks/returns and use of advice. However, given that our measure is strongly correlated with the composition of asset portfolios, in particular the positive relationship between numeracy and the propensity to hold stocks and private pensions (Banks and Oldfield, 2007), it is likely that our measure is correlated with financial literacy and knowledge.
Figs. 1a and 1b, taken from Banks and Oldfield (2007), show how this measure of numerical ability varies with age, sex and education. We use a simple classification of the population into three very broad education groups – Low education is defined as having no academic qualifications, medium education is defined as having O-levels or equivalent and high education is defined as having A-levels (or equivalent) or higher.
Figure 1.
a: Broad numeracy score, by age and education: Men
Source: Banks and Oldfield (2007)
b: Broad numeracy score, by age and education: Women
Source: Banks and Oldfield (2007)
Across all education groups, numerical ability as defined by these measures is greater for men than for women, and greater for younger individuals than for their older counterparts. These results mirror those in the more aggregated analysis in Steel et al. (2003) who simply use the average number of correct answers by group. The association between numerical ability and education is clearly evident in the data – as would be expected, groups with higher education have higher numerical ability. Despite this strong correlation, however, there is still a reasonably good distribution of the population across the four numerical abilities within each education group. This is particularly true for the younger sample members who will form the sample of ‘retirees’ on whom some of our later analysis will focus. There are individuals with low numerical ability in the highest education groups and individuals with high numerical ability in the low and medium education groups. The presence of such variation is important if we are to look at the separate effects of education and numeracy on retirement saving outcomes.
Notably, the age pattern in numerical ability is much stronger for the more educated groups, both for men and women, particularly at the top end. Thus the differences across education groups, whilst still present, are less marked among the oldest members of the ELSA sample in comparison to the 50–59 year olds. It should be repeated, however, that our numeracy data are currently cross-sectional in nature, and the presence of both differential mortality (the rich and cognitively able living longer than their poor and less able counterparts) and the presence of cohort differences in numeracy will mean that these correlations may not be the true age profiles. Whilst the true age profile will only be revealed in longitudinal data, it is possible to speculate on the sign of such biases. Differential mortality would reduce the extent to which we observe a decline with age in our sample and, to the extent that compound and simple interest was more likely to be taught to the older members of our sample, cohort differences in the nature of education would work the same way. In these circumstances the age related decline observed in Fig. 1 may even be an underestimate of the true decline with age.11
One further comment on cohort effects is warranted. While Fig. 1 shows substantial differences between the levels of numerical ability of men and women in the cohorts currently aged 50 and over taken together (i.e. the whole ELSA sample), this difference is unlikely to be indicative of differences between men and women for future cohorts. Younger generations of working-age women have more similar educational and labour market circumstances to their male counterparts and, if such circumstances lead to higher levels of numeracy, one might expect future generations of older women to be more comparable to men.
Of course, to argue that such differences in numeracy across individuals are the relevant ones for analysis of retirement savings and retirement saving trajectories, we need to believe that these differences, collected in 2002, are appropriate indicators of the previous lifetime differences across individuals, or at least the differences that have been present across the portion of life where individuals have been working in the labour market and making their consumption and saving decisions. Our data contain no data on numeracy levels prior to 2002, and therefore prior to age 50 for the youngest sample members, and nothing prior to even older ages for the others. While there is a wealth of research suggesting that numerical ability deteriorates with age, the evidence indicates that the magnitude of the deterioration is relatively small until at least retirement age (see Schaie, 1996; Office for National Statistics, 1997; Maitland et al., 2000; Schaie et al., 2004). Schaie (1996, p. 270) analyses longitudinal changes in a number of measures of cognitive ability, including numeracy, and finds that “these data [the Seattle Longitudinal Study] suggest that average decline in psychological competence may begin for some as early as the mid-50s, but that early decrement is of small magnitude until the mid-70s are reached.”
The implication of these studies for our results is that we can confident that, for most of our sample at least, the measure of numeracy that we have access to is indicative of the level respondents had throughout their working life. Moreover, in most of the empirical work that we present we focus on those immediately before and immediately after retirement age, that is before the largest falls in numerical ability manifest themselves. We must be careful, however, when analysing the behaviour of the oldest in our sample, which we touch on below in comparing wealth trajectories across cohorts. The deterioration in numeracy will bias these results, although the direction of the bias will be clear. We return to this issue when discussing the results that use multiple cohorts.
Turning to the measure of literacy, once again there is substantial covariation in cognitive abilities along this dimension with both the other measures of cognitive abilities and with education.12 To summarise the key issue for our purposes, Table 1 shows the proportions within each numeracy group that fall into each of the three literacy groups. A number of features are worthy of comment. Firstly, it can be seen that the literacy test was a relatively low level test – around two thirds of the sample were in the highest group (receiving a perfect score in the test) and only around one in seven were in the bottom category. These fractions show systematic variation with age and education along the same lines as the numeracy data described above, but this analysis is not presented here. A second feature of Table 1 is the strong correlation between the literacy and the numeracy scores. Indeed it is only really within the bottom two numeracy groups that there are substantial proportions of individuals receiving less than perfect scores in the literacy tests.
Table 1.
Correlation of numeracy and literacy scores
% distribution | Lowest literacy | Medium literacy | Highest literacy | Total |
---|---|---|---|---|
Lowest numeracy | 38.63 | 23.89 | 37.48 | 100.00 |
2 | 16.08 | 22.34 | 61.57 | 100.00 |
3 | 8.99 | 15.96 | 75.05 | 100.00 |
Highest numeracy | 5.85 | 10.40 | 83.75 | 100.00 |
All | 14.86 | 18.94 | 66.20 | 100.00 |
The final issue that warrants discussion before we turn to the results of our empirical analysis is that of individual decision making versus collective decision making by a couple. All of our analysis is carried out at the individual level. Therefore, where both members of a couple are in the sample, they each enter the analysis. However, many of the outcomes on which our analysis will focus in the following section are defined most meaningfully at the level of the couple. Indeed, for some measures such as wealth, they are only available at this level due to the way that they were collected in the ELSA survey instrument. As a result of this, we often control for whether the individual is a member of a couple or not and whether or not their spouse or partner is in employment.
Related to this is whether we should consider the possibility that the decisions of an individual in a couple might be impacted by the level of numerical ability of their spouse. After all, one may not need to be particularly numerate if one is married to someone who is so and they are taking an active role in the management of household saving and consumption decisions. When we analyze outcomes that are defined at the level of the couple (such as income and wealth), our strategy will be to allocate each individual the highest numeracy, literacy and executive scores within that couple, effectively assuming they benefit from full sharing of the abilities and knowledge of their partner. In models for individual outcomes, i.e. when we evaluate the accuracy of individuals’ work expectations, their expectations over the adequacy of their retirement income and their subjective life-satisfaction (Tables 8–10) we revert to using individual numeracy scores.13
Table 8.
OLS regressions for percent chance of inadequate resources at some time in the future, reported in 2006
Dependent variable: | Age 50–59 in 2002 | Age 60–69 in 2002 | Age 70+ in 2002 | |||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Expectations (2006) | b | Se | b | se | B | Se |
Expectations (2002) | 0.26*** | 0.03 | 0.26*** | 0.03 | 0.21*** | 0.03 |
Expectations * Num. Group I | −0.04 | 0.07 | −0.06 | 0.06 | −0.12* | 0.07 |
Expectations * Num. Group III | 0.11*** | 0.04 | 0.05 | 0.05 | 0.12** | 0.06 |
Expectations * Num. Group IV | 0.13** | 0.05 | 0.12* | 0.07 | −0.01 | 0.10 |
Numeracy Group I | 2.56 | 3.63 | 1.13 | 3.07 | 2.80 | 2.90 |
Numeracy Group III | −5.02*** | 1.88 | −4.46** | 2.09 | −3.93* | 2.29 |
Numeracy Group IV | −6.76*** | 2.18 | −5.52** | 2.80 | 1.12 | 3.79 |
Medium Education | 1.17 | 1.27 | 0.27 | 1.53 | −2.03 | 2.08 |
High Education | 0.19 | 1.37 | −1.74 | 1.59 | −3.95* | 2.02 |
Female | 2.98*** | 1.04 | 0.97 | 1.27 | 0.32 | 1.51 |
Couple | −0.63 | 1.26 | 0.81 | 1.35 | 3.29** | 1.46 |
2006 wealth quintile 2 | −6.19*** | 1.72 | −0.44 | 2.15 | −4.51* | 2.50 |
2006 wealth quintile 3 | −7.09*** | 1.64 | −3.30 | 2.11 | −4.36* | 2.64 |
2006 wealth quintile 4 | −10.54*** | 1.62 | −7.67*** | 2.19 | −10.51*** | 2.73 |
2006 wealth quintile 5 | −14.92*** | 1.68 | −10.69*** | 2.25 | −8.54*** | 2.92 |
Exec. Function Score | 0.09 | 1.41 | −2.31* | 1.36 | −0.13 | 1.60 |
Exec. Function Score^2 | −0.00 | 0.05 | 0.08 | 0.05 | 0.01 | 0.07 |
Memory Score | 1.96*** | 0.74 | 0.99 | 0.81 | 0.74 | 0.83 |
Memory Score^2 | −0.06*** | 0.02 | −0.03 | 0.02 | −0.02 | 0.03 |
Medium Literacy | −4.56** | 1.93 | −0.24 | 2.03 | −0.63 | 2.11 |
High literacy | −7.07*** | 1.68 | −3.72** | 1.78 | 1.43 | 1.84 |
Constant | 22.49** | 10.99 | 42.09*** | 10.43 | 19.03* | 10.57 |
N | 2,709 | 2,139 | 1,809 |
Table 10.
Life satisfaction, all ages and on retirement
Dependent variable: | Everyone | Retirees Only | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Life satisfaction (CASP19, 2006) | b | se | b | se |
Satisfaction (2002) | 0.507*** | 0.017 | 0.490*** | 0.053 |
Satisfaction * Num. Group I | 0.147*** | 0.037 | 0.206 | 0.127 |
Satisfaction * Num. Group III | −0.068** | 0.027 | 0.027 | 0.078 |
Satisfaction * Num. Group IV | 0.022 | 0.038 | 0.065 | 0.108 |
Numeracy Group I | −0.160** | 0.069 | −0.342 | 0.231 |
Numeracy Group III | 0.108** | 0.047 | −0.092 | 0.133 |
Numeracy Group IV | −0.005 | 0.064 | −0.093 | 0.178 |
Medium Education | −0.014 | 0.023 | 0.002 | 0.062 |
High Education | −0.020 | 0.023 | 0.040 | 0.065 |
Female | 0.003 | 0.018 | 0.105** | 0.053 |
Couple | 0.160*** | 0.021 | 0.219*** | 0.064 |
2006 wealth quintile 2 | 0.097*** | 0.031 | 0.089 | 0.102 |
2006 wealth quintile 3 | 0.119*** | 0.031 | 0.157* | 0.092 |
2006 wealth quintile 4 | 0.169*** | 0.031 | 0.273*** | 0.093 |
2006 wealth quintile 5 | 0.202*** | 0.032 | 0.329*** | 0.095 |
Exec. Function Score | 0.014 | 0.020 | −0.049 | 0.060 |
Exec. Function Score^2 | −0.000 | 0.001 | 0.002 | 0.002 |
Memory Score | 0.019* | 0.011 | 0.005 | 0.034 |
Memory Score^2 | −0.000 | 0.000 | −0.000 | 0.001 |
Medium Literacy | 0.025 | 0.030 | −0.055 | 0.093 |
High literacy | 0.007 | 0.027 | 0.015 | 0.078 |
Constant | 1.086*** | 0.153 | 1.654*** | 0.535 |
N | 5,805 | 684 |
Of course, to the extent that there is a perfect correlation between the abilities of each member of a couple, this may be an inconsequential assumption. Table 2, however, shows that the correlation in numeracy scores between men and women in couples in our data is far from perfect. Looking at the third row of this table as an example, of the 37% of men that are in numeracy group 3, only 11.46 percentage points are married to someone who is also in that numeracy group. Roughly half of the spouses (19.52 percentage points) are in numeracy group 2, with substantial fractions in both the lowest and the highest numeracy groups as well. Similar patterns exist for each of the levels of numeracy, whether one chooses to look along the rows (i.e. indexed by the male’s numeracy level) or down the columns (i.e. indexed by female’s numeracy level). Of course the fact that numeracy scores are higher for men than for women mean that there is more sample above the diagonal than below.
Table 2.
Correlation of numeracy scores within couples
2:Female 1:Male |
Worst | 2 | 3 | Best | All |
---|---|---|---|---|---|
Worst | 1.22 | 3.02 | 0.64 | 0.27 | 5.15 |
2 | 6.21 | 20.32 | 7.85 | 1.91 | 36.29 |
3 | 3.29 | 19.52 | 11.46 | 3.13 | 37.40 |
Best | 1.59 | 9.55 | 7.43 | 2.60 | 21.17 |
All | 12.31 | 52.41 | 27.37 | 7.90 | 100.00 |
The effect of this ‘household’ assumption on the correlation between numeracy and literacy is in fact to increase the correlation between the two dimensions even further. Table 3 replicates the analysis of Table 1 but this time uses the maximum levels for numeracy and literacy within a couple as opposed to the individual scores. Over 90% of the top numeracy group defined this way are also in the top literacy group, and the proportion of the lowest numeracy group falling into the lowest literacy group rises from 39% (at the individual level) to 43% when defined at the couple level.
Table 3.
Correlation of household maximum numeracy and literacy scores
% distribution | Lowest literacy | Medium literacy | Highest literacy | Total |
---|---|---|---|---|
Lowest numeracy | 42.64 | 21.57 | 35.79 | 100.00 |
2 | 13.77 | 19.15 | 67.08 | 100.00 |
3 | 6.23 | 10.19 | 83.58 | 100.00 |
Highest numeracy | 3.51 | 5.02 | 91.47 | 100.00 |
All | 10.48 | 13.00 | 76.52 | 100.00 |
3. Cognitive function and retirement saving trajectories
We now turn to our empirical investigation of whether, and if so how, the evolution of several key outcomes related to retirement and retirement-saving trajectories differ across groups defined by their numeracy status as measured at the initial ‘baseline’ of 2002. More specifically, we will focus on the evolution of wealth, retirement income, food consumption, expectations and life satisfaction over the four years following the baseline interview, i.e. from 2002 to 2006. Multivariate analysis is presented as a way of controlling for other potentially confounding baseline factors or any effects of imputation (particularly for wealth) on the observed profiles.
We begin by looking at trajectories for real net financial wealth, defined as the value of all financial assets (i.e. excluding private and state pensions and housing) less the value of any outstanding non-mortgage debts. With the longitudinal dimension of our data being relatively short (three observations over the period 2002 to 2006) we have no hope of using the now-standard approaches to attempt to distinguish age effects from time or cohort effects (see, for example, Deaton 1997, Section 2.7). Instead we confine ourselves to presenting unconditional wealth profiles by date of birth cohort and multivariate models of changes in wealth for broad age groups.
Fig. 2 presents average real net financial wealth profiles by age for cohorts defined by five-year date of birth intervals, with each date of birth cohort split into two groups according to the baseline numeracy score. The high numeracy group comprises those falling into groups 3 and 4 of our classification, as identified in Box 2 of Appendix 1, with the low numeracy group being the remainder. The use of five-year date of birth cohorts prohibits a finer numeracy classification since the number of observations in the extreme high and low numeracy groups would be insufficient in many cases to perform a credible analysis.
Figure 2.
Mean real net financial wealth profiles by date of birth and broad numeracy cohort
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from English Longitudinal Study of Ageing 2002 and 2006
Box 2. Construction of broad cognitive function categories.
Classification | Response to questions | Proportion of sample |
---|---|---|
Group I | Either: q2, q3, q4 all incorrect | 16.24% |
Or: q2 correct; q3, q4, q5 all incorrect | ||
Group II | At least one of q2, q3, q4, q5 incorrect; q6 incorrect | 46.46% |
Group III | Either: q2, q3, q4, q5 correct; q6 incorrect | 26.08% |
Or: At least one of q2, q3, q4, correct; q5, q6 correct | ||
Group IV | q2, q3, q4, q5, q6 correct | 11.22% |
Fig. 3 presents the 25th, 50th and 75th percentiles of the net financial wealth distribution at each age for each date-of-birth/numeracy cohort.14 The strong correlation between numeracy and the level of financial wealth is immediately apparent in each of these figures, with the wealth levels for the higher numeracy group substantially above those for the low numeracy group for all date-of-birth cohorts. In addition, there is some evidence of a more pronounced hump-shape in wealth profiles for the high numeracy group than for their low numeracy counterparts, particularly at the median and 75th percentile in Fig. 3. However, the differences in the hump-shape seem to come more from differences in the ‘cohort effects’ (i.e. the vertical shifts between the lines for each date of birth at similar ages) rather than from markedly different slopes of the age changes within each cohort. Moreover, it is worth noting that if it weren’t for the deterioration in numerical ability that is often experienced later in life then the hump-shape would be likely, under plausible assumptions, to be even more pronounced. Some of those that we observe with low numeracy in the older cohorts would probably have been in the high numeracy group if we had measured their cognitive ability in their 50s or 60s. Assuming that individuals switching numeracy groups came from the bottom of the distribution of numeracy within the baseline group and, on average, had lower wealth in later life (since previous work showed a positive correlation between numeracy and levels of wealth) we could conjecture that that transferring them from the low group to the high group at later ages, in order to create groups based on baseline rather than current numeracy levels, would reduce the average late-life wealth of the high numeracy group, thus accentuating the decline in wealth with age.
Figure 3.
Quantiles of real net financial wealth over age, by date of birth and broad numeracy cohort
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from English Longitudinal Study of Ageing 2002 and 2006
In order to investigate the relationship between wealth accumulation and numeracy in more detail we need to control for the many other factors that are correlated both with numeracy and wealth trajectories, not least education and other dimensions of cognitive function. Our approach is to use quantile regressions, presenting results for 50th percentile (the median) and in many cases the 25th and 75th percentiles also. Whilst this method is now standard, it is worth noting that the interpretation of a coefficient on variable x in a quantile regression at the θth quantile is that it gives the magnitude of the change in the θth quantile of the conditional distribution of the dependent variable in response to a marginal change increase in the value of x.15 Two things are important to note here. The first is that the interpretation of the quantile coefficient is not the effect of a change in x on the wealth of the individual with wealth at the 25th percentile. Should x change, that individual might not longer be located at that particular percentile. The effect is on the conditional quantile rather than the individual located at the conditional quantile. The second point to note is that nowhere here are we making claim to have uncovered a causal effect linking numeracy and wealth. At this stage, our research points to some interesting and important associations. A causal effect, if there is one, could run from wealth to numeracy or in the other direction. We return to this point in our conclusion.
We use two specifications to isolate the correlation between financial wealth and numeracy from other variables. For reasons that will become clear, we refer to these in the following discussion as our ‘levels of wealth specification’ and our ‘saving rate specification’.
The levels of wealth specification involves a set of quantile regressions of the level of wealth in 2006 on the level of wealth in 2002, dummies for numeracy, interactions of wealth in 2002 with the numeracy dummies and a number of other controls. This specification has the form:
FW2006=δFW2002+αN+γ(N·FW2002)+βX+φ(X·FW2002)+ε | (1) |
where FWy is financial wealth in year y, N is a vector of numeracy dummies capturing baseline levels of numeracy measured in 2002, and X contains other covariates including age dummies, sex dummies, a dummy for whether the respondent is in a couple, controls for education, other dimensions of cognitive function and dummies indicating whether (and to what extent) the measures of financial wealth contain imputed values. Notice that we interact the controls in X with financial wealth in 2002 to allow their effect to vary by the initial financial wealth of the individual concerned.
For the ‘saving rate specification’ we first define a saving rate as the difference in financial wealth as a ratio of average income, Ȳ as the average of reported income in 2002 and 2006. This saving rate therefore captures both ‘active’ saving (direct contributions to accounts) as well as ‘passive’ saving (capital gains or interest payments on existing balances that are retained in the fund and not withdrawn). We then perform a series of quantile regressions of this variable on numeracy and a number of other variables as follows, i.e.:
SR=αN+βX+ε, where SR=FW2006−FW2002Y¯ | (2) |
We split the sample roughly into those in ‘pre-retirement’ and ‘post-retirement’ years.16 In each of the models the reference group for numeracy is the second lowest as this group is the largest of the four groups. For the rest of the categorical variables, it is the least advantaged groups17 that are defined as the reference group, i.e. those with the lowest literacy, lowest education and lowest wealth.
Table 4a contains the results for the levels of wealth specification. In this specification, differences in wealth accumulation or decumulation between the two waves across numeracy groups are revealed by the coefficients on the interactions of wealth in wave one with each of the numeracy groups. A positive coefficient for any particular numeracy group interaction indicates that, conditional on wealth in wave one, that group has higher wealth in wave three relative to group II - therefore wealth accumulation was greater. The results in Table 4a shows that, prior to retirement (ages 50–61), asset accumulation is somewhat higher at all three quantiles and for almost all numeracy groups relative to the second numeracy group (the exception is that there is no significant difference between group I and group II at the 75th percentile).
Table 4.
a: Quantile regressions for change in real net financial wealth 2002–2006, levels of wealth specification | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Ages 50–61 in 2002 | Ages 65 and over in 2002 | |||||
25th percentile |
Median | 75th percentile |
25th percentile |
Median | 75th percentile |
|
Wealth in Wave 1 | 0.05 | 1.17*** | 2.75*** | −0.06** | −0.15*** | −0.30*** |
(0.10) | (0.14) | (0.26) | (0.03) | (0.05) | (0.10) | |
Numeracy group I | 0.36 | 0.19 | −0.71 | 0.14 | 0.01 | −0.40 |
(1.44) | (2.13) | (4.76) | (0.49) | (0.76) | (1.69) | |
Numeracy group III | 0.67 | 1.45 | 4.42** | −0.28 | −0.07 | −0.85 |
(0.69) | (0.97) | (2.02) | (0.32) | (0.48) | (1.10) | |
Numeracy group IV | 0.06 | 0.71 | 15.45*** | 2.43*** | 5.09*** | 11.05*** |
(0.80) | (1.13) | (2.38) | (0.50) | (0.75) | (1.67) | |
Wealth1*Num. group I | 0.32*** | 0.09** | −0.03 | 0.03** | −0.12*** | −0.11*** |
(0.02) | (0.04) | (0.05) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.04) | |
Wealth1*Num. group III | 0.04*** | 0.15*** | 0.25*** | 0.07*** | 0.06*** | 0.15*** |
(0.01) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.01) | |
Wealth1*Num. group IV | 0.10*** | 0.27*** | 0.23*** | 0.05*** | −0.06*** | −0.10*** |
(0.01) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.00) | (0.01) | (0.01) | |
Medium Education | −0.19 | 0.31 | 4.89** | 1.50*** | 0.28 | 3.11** |
(0.66) | (0.94) | (2.03) | (0.39) | (0.57) | (1.28) | |
High Education | 0.65 | 3.90*** | 16.04*** | 3.23*** | 4.48*** | 13.00*** |
(0.73) | (1.01) | (2.19) | (0.40) | (0.59) | (1.30) | |
Exec. Function Score | 0.03 | −0.49 | 2.09 | 0.00 | −0.50 | −3.87*** |
(0.83) | (1.15) | (2.64) | (0.31) | (0.47) | (1.05) | |
Exec. Function Score^2 | 0.00 | 0.03 | −0.05 | −0.00 | 0.02 | 0.15*** |
(0.03) | (0.04) | (0.09) | (0.01) | (0.02) | (0.04) | |
Memory Score | −0.28 | −0.84 | −2.30* | −0.06 | −0.54** | 0.18 |
(0.49) | (0.67) | (1.39) | (0.16) | (0.25) | (0.57) | |
Memory Score^2 | 0.01 | 0.03 | 0.06* | 0.00 | 0.03*** | 0.01 |
(0.01) | (0.02) | (0.04) | (0.00) | (0.01) | (0.02) | |
Medium literacy | 0.48 | −0.09 | −1.59 | −0.85* | −1.04 | −1.05 |
(1.26) | (1.80) | (3.94) | (0.46) | (0.71) | (1.62) | |
High literacy | 1.45 | 1.10 | 2.92 | −0.17 | −0.70 | −1.16 |
(1.07) | (1.50) | (3.23) | (0.41) | (0.63) | (1.43) | |
Constant | 1.62 | 6.87 | 4.27 | 0.09 | 6.89** | 24.41*** |
(6.71) | (9.36) | (21.06) | (2.04) | (3.26) | (7.12) | |
N | 3,222 | 3,222 | 3,222 | 2,990 | 2,990 | 2,990 |
b: Quantile regressions for change in real net financial wealth 2002–2006, saving rate specification | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Ages 50–61 in 2002 | Ages 65 and over in 2002 | |||||
25th percentile |
Median | 75th percentile |
25th percentile |
Median | 75th percentile |
|
Numeracy group I | 0.16 | 0.03 | −0.08 | 0.13 | 0.01 | −0.01 |
(0.17) | (0.06) | (0.30) | (0.15) | (0.04) | (0.12) | |
Numeracy group III | −0.11 | 0.07*** | 0.41*** | −0.19** | −0.01 | 0.05 |
(0.07) | (0.03) | (0.12) | (0.09) | (0.03) | (0.08) | |
Numeracy group IV | −0.14* | 0.16*** | 0.70*** | −0.80*** | −0.17*** | 0.32*** |
(0.08) | (0.03) | (0.14) | (0.13) | (0.04) | (0.11) | |
Medium Education | −0.03 | 0.02 | 0.26** | −0.22** | −0.02 | 0.18** |
(0.07) | (0.03) | (0.12) | (0.10) | (0.03) | (0.09) | |
High Education | −0.09 | 0.07*** | 0.40*** | −0.43*** | −0.03 | 0.36*** |
(0.07) | (0.03) | (0.13) | (0.10) | (0.03) | (0.09) | |
Exec. Function Score | −0.05 | 0.03 | 0.17 | −0.13 | −0.04 | −0.11 |
(0.09) | (0.03) | (0.15) | (0.09) | (0.03) | (0.08) | |
Exec. Function Score^2 | 0.00 | −0.00 | −0.01 | 0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | |
Memory Score | 0.02 | −0.01 | −0.08 | 0.03 | 0.00 | −0.01 |
(0.05) | (0.02) | (0.09) | (0.05) | (0.01) | (0.04) | |
Memory Score^2 | −0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 | −0.00 | 0.00 | 0.00 |
(0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | (0.00) | |
Medium literacy | 0.18 | 0.05 | 0.24 | 0.07 | 0.02 | 0.03 |
(0.14) | (0.05) | (0.23) | (0.13) | (0.04) | (0.11) | |
High literacy | 0.02 | 0.04 | 0.15 | −0.16 | −0.00 | 0.15 |
(0.11) | (0.04) | (0.19) | (0.12) | (0.03) | (0.10) | |
Constant | −0.22 | −0.13 | −0.03 | 0.38 | 0.25 | 0.88* |
(0.73) | (0.26) | (1.25) | (0.62) | (0.19) | (0.53) | |
N | 3,222 | 3,222 | 3,222 | 2,990 | 2,990 | 2,990 |
A different pattern is found after retirement age. In moving from the younger sample to the older sample, the relationship between the least numerate and second least numerate switches. Recall that in the pre-retirement sample the least numerate were accumulating wealth at a faster rate. In the post-retirement sample on the other hand, the least numerate group were (except at the 25th percentile) accumulating wealth at a slower rate. There is also a switch in the relative saving patterns of the most numerate group and the omitted group. Recall that in the pre-retirement sample, the former group is accumulating wealth at a faster rate than the omitted group (at the 25th, 50th and 75th conditional percentiles). However, after retirement, at the median and 75th percentile, this group accumulate wealth at a slower rate than the second numeracy group. Put simply, the time path of median wealth accumulation is more hump-shaped in the top numeracy group relative to the omitted group. Note that these differences exist whilst controlling for the possible confounding effects of education differences, literacy and other dimensions of cognitive function, and indeed baseline levels of net financial wealth.
Table 4b looks at this same issue using the saving rate specification. At the median, there is additional evidence of the hump-shape in saving behaviour that we noted above. The most numerate group save the most (as a proportion of their income) pre-retirement and then save the least (or dis-save the most) post-retirement. The pattern is different at the 25th and 75th percentiles. At the 25th percentile the most numerate group have the lowest saving rates both pre- and post-retirement and at the 75th percentile have the highest saving rates, again both preand post-retirement. This is evidence that, conditional on those other characteristics we include in these regressions, there is more variation in the saving rates among the most numerate than there is among other groups. Testing relative differences between groups other than group II reveals that there are many significant differences at all three percentiles between the group IV and the other groups both pre-and post-retirement, suggesting that being highly numerate makes a difference to asset accumulation but that the differences between groups at lower levels of numeracy are less apparent.
4. Replacement rates, expectations and subjective well-being at retirement
One of the advantages of the ELSA data is that it contains rich information in many dimensions, not just the financial and cognitive dimensions that we have used so far. In particular, the ELSA instrument includes a battery of questions relating to individuals’ expectations of the future as well as various modules of questions on subjective quality of life, mental well-being and life-satisfaction. These data provide us with the opportunity of looking at whether there is variation across numeracy groups in considerably broader retirement outcomes than those we have looked at so far. We begin this analysis, however, by looking at the changes in consumption and income that occur immediately around the time of retirement, which will fundamentally relate to the trajectories of these broader outcomes as individuals approach and arrive at retirement.
4.1 Replacement rates
Financial wealth is only one element of retirement resources, and what is more, it is an element that is of differing relative importance across the socio-economic groups – other sources of retirement resources include private and state pensions as well as other welfare benefits. In order to test whether there is more ‘smoothing’ across pre- and post-retirement states it would be more appropriate to look at some measure of replacement rates for net income, or else changes in consumption expenditures. Net incomes (including asset and pension income) are completely measured in the ELSA survey so replacement rates are straightforward to compute. When it comes to expenditure changes, the only item of non-housing expenditures measured consistently across the three waves of data that we use is food spending. Expenditure on other non-food items was collected in 2004 and 2006, but we do not observe enough retirements between those years to be able to facilitate a detailed analysis.
Our analysis of replacement rates simply compares levels of income and food consumption before and after individuals are observed to retire, regardless of how old they were when they retired. As such, our sample is limited to the 700 individuals that are observed retiring in the four-year window and for whom we have full information on all the financial and cognitive variables required for our analysis. Table 5 presents unconditional summary statistics for the distribution of net income replacement rates for retirees between 2002 and 2006 across the four numeracy groups and for the distribution of changes in weekly food expenditures. For income, the distribution is somewhat more compressed for those with the lowest numeracy but other than that there are no marked differences across groups. On the spending side the differences are more apparent – with spending falling on retirement by more for the less numerate.18 Indeed food spending rose at the median for those in the most numerate group. This pattern – the positive gradient between food spending replacement rates with respect to numerical ability – is true for all three quantiles of the distribution presented in the table.
Table 5.
Distribution of income and food consumption replacement rates, by numeracy group
Outcome | Numeracy Group | p25 | Median | p75 |
---|---|---|---|---|
Net Income Replacement Rate | I | 43.97 | 57.35 | 99.06 |
II | 41.20 | 69.54 | 97.27 | |
III | 45.66 | 70.01 | 99.59 | |
IV | 40.37 | 69.15 | 101.11 | |
Food Replacement Rate | I | 64.84 | 77.82 | 108.49 |
II | 71.45 | 95.01 | 116.65 | |
III | 74.88 | 95.54 | 117.68 | |
IV | 76.08 | 105.99 | 125.48 |
We also investigated the extent to which replacement rates vary with numeracy after controlling for characteristics such as age of retirement, level of wealth, work status of spouse etc. The regression results on most individual characteristics (which are not presented but are available from the authors on request) are largely in line with our expectations. Replacement rates tend to be lower for those who retire earlier, and are higher for those whose spouse remains in work (since our measure of income is at the level of the couple19). We find no significant correlation, however, between either measure of replacement rates and numerical ability. This provides some evidence (though it should be noted that this analysis is based on the relatively small sample of 700 individuals who we observe retiring between 2002 and 2006) that the variation in replacement rates across numeracy groups can largely be explained by characteristics that are correlated with numeracy rather than numeracy itself.
One way in which these relatively weak differences between groups in terms of changes in living standards around the time of retirement can be reconciled with the sharper differences in financial wealth trajectories, would be for the other determinants of economic well-being – namely private and state pensions and other state benefits – to be changing differentially across groups. Table 6, which looks at the percentage of income that comes from the state (either state benefits or pensions) by numeracy group for the same sample of retirees that we used for the evidence in Table 5. Almost 80% of income for the least numerate group comes from the state compared to just 30% for the most numerate group. So whilst the least numerate group have less wealth and are less likely to invest in risky assets, these numbers suggest that in fact, for this group, this may be an entirely sensible strategy because in retirement, they will simply rely on the state and enjoy a relatively high replacement rate. If this was the case we would not expect changes in expectations and changes in subjective measures of well-being to be correlated with numerical or cognitive ability. We turn to this topic in the next sections.
Table 6.
Income decomposition post-retirement for those retiring between waves 1 and 3
Percentage of income from the state in wave three |
|
---|---|
Numeracy group I | 79.4 |
Numeracy group II | 59.0 |
Numeracy group III | 37.2 |
Numeracy group IV | 30.9 |
4.2 Expectations of retirement and retirement incomes
In common with a number of ageing studies, ELSA collects quantitative information on subjective expectations of a number of future events using the ‘per cent chance’ methodology. Individuals are asked to assess the chances of future events on a scale of 0 to 100, where 0 means there is no chance and 100 means the individual is certain the event will occur. Whilst ELSA collects expectations data on mortality probabilities, housing values, future health outcomes and inheritances/bequests, we focus here on two particular dimensions of expectations. First we look at the expectations of future work for those currently in work. For the large majority of those working at our baseline sample, these expectations can be assessed directly against the subsequent outcomes over the period that the expectations were referring to. Second, we look at individuals’ subjective assessment of the chances that their financial resources will, at some point in the future, prove inadequate to meet their needs.
Taking employment probabilities first, we divide up the sample that were employed at wave 1 into groups according to their self-reported chances of employment at future ages.20 For those that crossed the age referred to in the question between 2002 and 2006 we calculate the fraction that actually were in work, split by the two broad numeracy groups representing the bottom two and top two numeracy categories respectively.21 In Fig. 4 these employment outcomes are plotted against the employment expectations for each of the two groups.22 Once again, whilst there are differences between the groups, and these differences go the way that one might suspect – the relationship for the higher numeracy group is slightly steeper on average, representing a stronger correlation between expectation and outcomes – the differences between groups are not particularly striking.
Figure 4.
Accuracy of future work expectations: Proportion in work in 2006, by per cent chances in 2002
Source: Authors’ calculations using data from English Longitudinal Study of Ageing 2002 and 2006
In order to investigate this relationship further and to control for other factors, Table 7 presents a simple model of whether the individual is working in wave 3 as a function of their wave 1 expectation. To facilitate a straightforward interpretation of the marginal effects with so many interaction terms we use a linear probability model, although the results are qualitatively similar if we use a probit model. On the right hand side, in addition to the usual demographic variables included in previous models, we also include the expectations of working reported in wave 1. We run the regression for everyone age under 65 (first two columns of numbers) and also for those aged under 65 who are working at wave 1 (second two columns of numbers). To assess the extent to which individuals in different numeracy groups are better at predicting their work probability, we interact work expectations with the numeracy dummies.
Table 7.
Linear probability model for probability of working in wave 3
Dependent variable: | All <65 | <65 and working in Wave 1 | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Working in Wave 3*100 | b | se | b | se |
Expectations (2002) | 0.58*** | 0.03 | 0.27*** | 0.04 |
Expectations * Num. Group I | −0.03 | 0.07 | −0.13 | 0.10 |
Expectations * Num. Group III | 0.04 | 0.04 | 0.10* | 0.05 |
Expectations * Num. Group IV | −0.00 | 0.05 | 0.04 | 0.06 |
Numeracy Group I | 8.64** | 4.16 | 15.56** | 7.58 |
Numeracy Group III | −1.92 | 2.61 | −7.88* | 4.03 |
Numeracy Group IV | 2.42 | 3.18 | −1.38 | 4.71 |
Medium Education | 4.50** | 1.81 | 4.35** | 2.13 |
High Education | 3.98** | 1.91 | 3.77* | 2.24 |
Female | −10.29*** | 1.58 | −9.40*** | 1.83 |
Couple | 8.38*** | 1.78 | 4.39** | 2.21 |
2006 wealth quintile 2 | 1.88 | 2.43 | 0.06 | 3.06 |
2006 wealth quintile 3 | 7.24*** | 2.31 | −1.20 | 2.80 |
2006 wealth quintile 4 | 6.11*** | 2.30 | −1.71 | 2.78 |
2006 wealth quintile 5 | 2.05 | 2.35 | −5.84** | 2.88 |
Exec. Function Score | 4.28** | 1.85 | 3.34 | 2.29 |
Exec. Function Score^2 | −0.13** | 0.07 | −0.10 | 0.08 |
Memory Score | 0.81 | 1.02 | 0.60 | 1.33 |
Memory Score^2 | −0.01 | 0.03 | −0.01 | 0.04 |
Medium Literacy | 5.43** | 2.67 | 6.63** | 3.31 |
High literacy | 4.78** | 2.32 | 3.53 | 2.85 |
Constant | −51.33*** | 14.33 | −8.56 | 19.21 |
N | 3,265 | 2,306 |
The coefficient on expectations in 2002 reveals that there is a positive and strongly significant correlation between expectations of working in 2002 and the probability of working in wave 3: everything else equal, for every percentage point increase in expectations in 2002 for those aged under 65 in this group, there is a 0.6 percentage point increase in the probability of working at wave 3. The coefficients on the interaction terms of expectations in 2002 with numeracy in Table 7 show how these correlations vary by numeracy group, with group II being the reference group. There are no significant differences between numeracy groups in their ability to predict the probability of working at wave 3.
Turning to the second set of coefficients in Table 7, we might expect those who were not working in wave one to be better able to predict their work probability in wave three since exiting the labour market is often a permanent change in state (although there could of course have been differences across numeracy groups as to the extent to which individuals understood this). To evaluate whether or not this is true, in the second two columns of numbers we restrict our sample to those aged under 65 who were working in wave 1. Whilst the correlation of expectations and outcomes that we previously noted is still observed, we find that on average this group are less able to predict their probability of working than for the whole sample: for every percentage point increase in the expectation of working at wave 1 there is an increase of 0.3 percentage points in the probability of working at wave 3 (this compares to a coefficient of 0.6 for the whole sample). Furthermore, we find here, as we found above when our analysis used the entire sample rather than simply those in work in wave 1, that there is very little difference between numeracy groups in their ability to predict the probability of working.
Turning to the second expectation that we analyse, namely the per cent chances that future incomes will be insufficient to meet future needs, it is clear that there is no concrete benchmark or outcome against which we can assess the expectations of different groups of the population. Instead, we therefore look at the stability and the correlation of these expectations over time within individuals. If a group of the population are consistently surprised (or underprepared) at retirement then we might expect to see systematic revisions of this expectation for that group.
It is certainly true that, on the surface, there is less stability in the financial expectations of the less numerate groups than in their more numerate counterparts. Looking at the lowest two groups together, the correlation across waves of their expectations of adequate financial resources is 0.3 for (both for the entire under-65 sample and 0.25 for those observed retiring between waves). The corresponding numbers for the top two numeracy groups are 0.44 for the entire under-65 sample and 0.43 for the retiring sample. But how much of these differences are simply a result of confounding factors?
To assess this in more detail, Table 8 provides an analysis of the correlations between expectations in 2006 and those collected in 2002, with the correlation allowed to depend on numeracy and a substantial set of controls for other factors. In addition, we split our analysis into three age groups to capture the fact that future financial insecurity may change as individuals move towards, into and through, retirement. Table 8 shows that (everything else equal), for the reference group there is a positive and significant, but somewhat small, correlation over time between financial insecurity expectations. Looking at differences in this correlation across numeracy group reveals that the biggest differences are found in the youngest age group where we find that relative to group II, groups III and IV have more stable expectations over future financial insecurity. For older age groups, there is also some weak evidence that these expectations are more stable for those with more numerical ability, though many of the differences between the coefficients of interest are either insignificant or only marginally significant at the 5% level.
While the relationship between wealth and the level of concern about future financial insecurity is negative for those aged 50–59, it is perhaps surprising there is only weaker evidence of this for the older groups. While those in the wealthiest 40% of the population are less likely to be concerned about the future than those in the bottom wealth quintile, there are no statistically significant differences (at the 5% level) between those in either the third or second quintiles and those in the bottom quintile in either the 60–69 or 70+ age groups.
To look specifically at the issue of ‘shocks’ to expectations around the time of retirement, Table 9 presents the same analysis for both the all-age sample and the sample of only those observed retiring between waves. The intertemporal correlation in expectations is no different for the reference group in the retirees samples than it is in the whole sample, although it is estimated less precisely for the former as a result of the considerably smaller sample size. There is a weak (statistically significant at the 10% level) effect of being in the lowest numeracy group on the change in expectations on retirement, but no significant differences between the other three groups. For the retiring sample, the correlations between wealth and the level of financial insecurity are, if anything, slightly more pronounced than in the all-age sample or either of the two younger aged samples in the previous table.
Table 9.
OLS regressions for percent chance of inadequate resources at some time in the future, all ages and on retirement
Dependent variable: | Everyone | Retirees only | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Expectations (2006) | b | se | b | Se |
Expectations (2002) | 0.244*** | 0.016 | 0.258*** | 0.050 |
Expectations * Num. Group I | −0.067* | 0.036 | −0.215* | 0.115 |
Expectations * Num. Group III | 0.100*** | 0.027 | 0.044 | 0.076 |
Expectations * Num. Group IV | 0.112*** | 0.038 | 0.075 | 0.103 |
Numeracy Group I | 1.801 | 1.782 | 7.551 | 6.292 |
Numeracy Group III | −4.669*** | 1.185 | −2.290 | 3.412 |
Numeracy Group IV | −5.753*** | 1.551 | −6.027 | 4.243 |
Medium Education | −0.033 | 0.883 | 2.668 | 2.384 |
High Education | −1.595* | 0.925 | 0.843 | 2.490 |
Female | 1.328* | 0.711 | 4.501** | 2.037 |
Couple | 0.956 | 0.775 | 1.874 | 2.347 |
2006 wealth quintile 2 | −4.689*** | 1.162 | −4.130 | 3.814 |
2006 wealth quintile 3 | −5.654*** | 1.163 | −8.323** | 3.522 |
2006 wealth quintile 4 | −10.017*** | 1.185 | −8.539** | 3.606 |
2006 wealth quintile 5 | −12.584*** | 1.236 | −17.000*** | 3.683 |
Exec. Function Score | −0.646 | 0.775 | 0.721 | 2.352 |
Exec. Function Score^2 | 0.021 | 0.029 | −0.021 | 0.087 |
Memory Score | 1.283*** | 0.419 | 0.983 | 1.257 |
Memory Score^2 | −0.039*** | 0.012 | −0.021 | 0.035 |
Medium Literacy | −1.328 | 1.153 | −8.062** | 3.488 |
High literacy | −2.873*** | 1.009 | −7.735*** | 2.913 |
Constant | 20.832*** | 5.587 | 20.816 | 18.656 |
N | 6,657 | 778 |
4.3 Subjective well-being around the time of retirement
Our results so far suggest that although numeracy is correlated with financial wealth accumulation behaviour we find only weak evidence to suggest that it matters for more fundamental outcomes such as replacement rates or accuracy of expectations. In this subsection, we turn to direct measures of subjective well-being to assess whether these differences in numeracy are correlated with changes in welfare on retirement. We are able use two measures of subjective well-being that were collected in both the 2002 and 2006 waves: The first is a single item taken from the CASP19 measure of quality of life23 which asks how often individuals feel “satisfied with the way my life has turned out”. We translate the four possible answers (often, sometimes, not often, never) into a 4 point scale from 1–4 with the highest value relating to the ‘often’ category. The second measure is one dimension of the General Health Questionnaire 12-item measure of mental health (GHQ12) which asks how often the respondent has recently “been feeling reasonably happy, all things considered”. Again, we translate the four possible responses (not at all, no more than usual, rather more than usual, much more than usual) into a scale from one to four with the highest category representing the highest level of ‘happiness’. Since we are interested particularly in changes or shocks around the time of retirement we once again run a simple regression of the level of subjective well-being on its previous value for both the whole sample and only those retiring between waves one and three.
Table 10 reports results from the CASP19 measure of life satisfaction and Table 11 contains results from the corresponding analysis for the GHQ12 happiness measure. Broadly speaking, the former analysis shows higher life satisfaction for women, for those in couples and for higher wealth groups, for both the whole sample and the sample of retirees. These patterns are mirrored in Table 11 for the current happiness measure although the differences between groups are smaller and are not typically significant for the sample of retirees. Nevertheless, these cross-sectional correlations are all in accordance with the now common finding in economists’ empirical work on happiness and subjective well-being.
Table 11.
‘Current’ subjective well-being, all ages and on retirement
Dependent variable: | Everyone | Retirees Only | ||
---|---|---|---|---|
Happiness (GHQ12, 2006) | b | se | b | se |
Happiness (2002) | 0.225*** | 0.019 | 0.177*** | 0.062 |
Happiness * Num. Group I | −0.008 | 0.044 | −0.258 | 0.180 |
Happiness * Num. Group III | 0.055* | 0.030 | 0.025 | 0.089 |
Happiness * Num. Group IV | 0.110*** | 0.040 | 0.227** | 0.105 |
Numeracy Group I | 0.040 | 0.090 | 0.542 | 0.343 |
Numeracy Group III | −0.118* | 0.061 | −0.069 | 0.178 |
Numeracy Group IV | −0.227*** | 0.081 | −0.408* | 0.212 |
Medium Education | 0.022 | 0.015 | −0.005 | 0.043 |
High Education | 0.046*** | 0.016 | −0.025 | 0.045 |
Female | −0.008 | 0.012 | 0.033 | 0.037 |
Couple | 0.006 | 0.014 | 0.034 | 0.043 |
2006 wealth quintile 2 | 0.038* | 0.021 | 0.029 | 0.071 |
2006 wealth quintile 3 | 0.059*** | 0.021 | 0.017 | 0.063 |
2006 wealth quintile 4 | 0.060*** | 0.021 | 0.069 | 0.065 |
2006 wealth quintile 5 | 0.079*** | 0.021 | 0.045 | 0.066 |
Exec. Function Score | −0.014 | 0.013 | −0.067 | 0.042 |
Exec. Function Score^2 | 0.001 | 0.000 | 0.003* | 0.002 |
Memory Score | −0.007 | 0.007 | −0.010 | 0.024 |
Memory Score^2 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.000 | 0.001 |
Medium Literacy | −0.000 | 0.020 | −0.002 | 0.065 |
High literacy | 0.001 | 0.018 | 0.027 | 0.055 |
Constant | 2.398*** | 0.112 | 3.034*** | 0.412 |
N | 5,848 | 697 |
There are no consistent patterns emerging across numeracy groups, or any other dimension of cognitive function for that matter, either in the cross-sectional level of well-being or in the persistence of well-being between waves. Of particular interest, there is no evidence of differential shocks to life-satisfaction on retirement across numeracy groups, although it should be noted that given the size of the retiring sample, the power of these tests is limited. Moreover, there is no evidence of any less persistence in this measure in the retiring sample than there is in the all-ages sample, perhaps not surprising given the largely retrospective and evaluative nature of the question. Looking at the measure of ‘current’ well-being, as measured by the GHQ12 measure in Table 11, the correlation between changes on retirement and numeracy are once again weak and suggest that the more numerate group display greater stability over time in their answers. This, if anything, indicates a pattern opposite to that suggested by the analysis of the CASP19 measure. This reinforces the contention that there is little evidence of systematic and consistent gradients in the stability of subjective measures of well-being with respect to numeracy among those who retire, at least given the data currently available.
5. Conclusions
As the United Kingdom has moved more towards a system of individual provision for retirement income, the importance of an individual’s or household’s abilities to make the right choices when it comes to providing for their retirement – either in terms of the decision to accumulate financial wealth, the form in which such wealth should be accumulated, or the decision of when to retire and how that might affect one’s retirement income – has increased. In addition to preferences, key factors that will contribute to individuals’ choices are the information the individual has about the relevant options available and their ability to process this information. Indeed the UK government’s ‘informed choice’ agenda has explicitly targeted improvements in these latter two dimensions, along with simplification of the private savings environment, as a goal for government policy (Sandler 2002; Pickering, 2002).
This paper has looked at broad retirement wealth and retirement-related trajectories by groups defined by cognitive function, numeracy, literacy, education and wealth. Whilst previous analysis has identified marked differences in portfolios, asset-holding behaviour and knowledge of pension arrangements across numeracy groups, the analysis in this paper has demonstrated that it is much harder to find substantial effects on subsequent trajectories for the broader retirement outcomes we have studied. In particular, whilst there may be some tentative evidence for a more ‘hump shaped’ profile of wealth accumulation amongst more numerate individuals this does not systematically translate into differences in replacement rates, either defined as ratios of post-retirement to pre-retirement incomes, ratios of post-retirement to pre-retirement consumption or broader changes in well-being on retirement. And whilst there is some evidence for less informed expectations of the future amongst lower numeracy older individuals it is perhaps hard to separate this from any effects of differential reporting behaviour across numeracy groups or from genuine differences in the shocks and variability of economic circumstances that these groups might face.
There are a number of possible explanations for these findings. One is simply that predicting individual level changes in panel data from permanent ‘baseline’ differences across individuals is always going to be a challenge, particularly when outcome variables (such as wealth) are measured with error and the available time-series of longitudinal information is short. Another important contributory factor, however, appears to be that the vast majority of retirement resources for low numeracy individuals does not come from privately saved (non-pension) financial assets and hence portfolio differences have little consequences for differences in broader retirement outcomes. Put simply, the fact that the less numerate hold systematically different portfolios may well be only of second order importance for determining retirement outcomes since the latter are driven much more strongly by state pensions, other components of the welfare system, informal insurance mechanisms, and perhaps housing.
Perhaps this is not surprising. As Browning and Lusardi (1996) discuss in their survey article on the life-cycle consumption model, non-life-cycle behaviours (such as those hypothesised in behavioural-type models) are much more likely to be evident in portfolio choices than at the more aggregate consumption-savings margin, since ‘behavioural’ consumers will still smooth their consumption one way or the other. A similar phenomenon could well be at play with regard to lower numeracy or less financially literate individuals. However, this is not to say that numeracy and financial literacy do not matter, nor that they will not become more important over time as the degree of individual provision and the complexity of financial institutions and portfolio options increases.
Whilst suggesting some interesting relationships, our findings are probably best viewed as pointing to directions for future research that would allow a more concrete investigation into some of the empirical processes and causal mechanisms at work. Such research should certainly exploit the fact that the English Longitudinal Study of Ageing is a continuing longitudinal study and hence new insights will become available as we get the ability to follow the wealth trajectories of individuals for longer periods pre- and post-retirement, to control for age-related changes in cognitive function and numeracy, and to observe a greater number of individuals, and cohorts of individuals, retiring. The analysis of such data would be most profitably combined with a structural model of consumption, saving and portfolio choice over the lifecycle which could be used to produce concrete predictions about the level and changes of wealth holdings and retirement assets that would be expected from an ‘optimising’ consumer with varying life-time circumstances and all the incentives and disincentives to accumulate wealth that are generated by the United Kingdom social security system. A well-calibrated model of this form, with earnings processes differing by household type and a realistic modelling of pensions and welfare payments, could deliver predictions against which the observed trajectories of individuals of differing numerical or cognitive ability could be compared, in order to assess whether such individuals are indeed further from the optimal profile than are their more able counterparts.
In addition, the development of cognitive and numerical tests that can, with relatively few questions, distinguish in a more graduated way between individuals at the extremes of the cognitive functioning distribution would be useful since at present the possible splits are somewhat coarse. This will be particularly important for studying working-age individuals and those at or approaching retirement whose choices may be the most complex. Combining such data with individual level data on financial literacy, the information individuals have for planning purposes and the use of advice would offer another promising avenue for future research.
Acknowledgements
We are grateful to Luigi Guiso and Tom Crossley for comments on an earlier draft of this paper and to the US National Institute on Ageing and the UK Economic and Social Research Council for funding this research. Data from the English Longitudinal Study of Ageing (ELSA) were supplied by the ESRC Data Archive. ELSA was developed by researchers based at University College London, the Institute for Fiscal Studies and the National Centre for Social Research, with funding provided by the US National Institute on Aging and a consortium of UK government departments coordinated by the Office for National Statistics. Responsibility for interpretation of the data, as well as for any errors, is the authors’ alone.
APPENDIX 1
Derivation of numeracy classification variables
Box 1a. Numeracy items in ELSA questionnaire.
-
q1)
If you buy a drink for 85 pence and pay with a one pound coin, how much change should you get?
-
q2)
In a sale, a shop is selling all items at half price. Before the sale a sofa costs £300. How much will it cost in the sale?
-
q3)
If the chance of getting a disease is 10 per cent, how many people out of 1,000 would be expect to get the disease?
-
q4)
A second hand car dealer is selling a car for £6,000. This is two-thirds of what it cost new. How much did the car cost new?
-
q5)
If 5 people all have the winning numbers in the lottery and the prize is £2 million, how much will each of them get?
-
q6)
Let’s say you have £200 in a savings account. The account earns ten per cent interest per year. How much will you have in the account at the end of two years?
Footnotes
1
A substantial set of issues relate to the distinctions between intelligence, cognitive and the more specific dimensions such as numeracy, literacy and executive function that we use here. We do not discuss it in detail here but note that a number of studies look at the link between dimensions (e.g. Gottfredson (2004) who looks at whether intelligence or ‘general ability’ is the factor that underlies the many correlations between socioeconomic status and the large array of health outcomes (i.e. knowledge, behaviours, morbidity and mortality) or the studies cited therein). In an important paper that sets out an overall framework for structuring the future analysis of cognitive skills in economics, Borghans et al. (2008) argue that economic parameters such as discount rates or risk aversion coefficients are likely to be produced by both cognitive and non-cognitive (personality) traits and that distinguishing the two empirically can be a challenge given that both evolve over the life-cycle albeit at different rates at different ages.
2
By increasing the cognitive load the “working memory” capacity of the brain is decreased. Since working memory capacity is almost perfectly correlated with general cognitive function, this manipulation is argued to effectively reduce cognitive ability.
4
A framing effect is where the interpretation of a number depends on the way in which it is presented. For example, if meat is presented as being “25% fat” or “75% fat-free”.
5
Lusardi and Mitchell (2007) show similar results for a broader measure of financial literacy using data from the US Health and Retirement Study.
6
The UK pension system is highly complex and has been repeatedly reformed over the last twenty years with the result that individuals in the age group analysed here will have a very diverse set of public and private pension arrangements and incentives. Such differences could in principal present interesting opportunities for analysis within the context of a broad structural model relating numeracy to retirement saving outcomes. We leave such an analysis for future research, but note that interested readers are referred to Banks and Emmerson (2000) for an overview of the broad structure of the pension system, or Bozio et al. (2010) for a more detailed examination of recent reforms to state pension provision.
7
Household or couple-specific measures such as housing characteristics or financial wealth (when finances are kept jointly) are only collected once from each household/couple. Individual circumstances such as health or job details are collected from each adult either privately or in the presence of other household members according to the choice of the respondents. Cognitive function tests are delivered in a private module to each adult conducted in the absence of other household members.
8
The data that we use in this paper contains only one observation on both numeracy and literacy, so our analysis will not be able to look at changes in these dimensions and how such changes correlate with changes in financial (or any other) circumstances. The 2008 wave of ELSA data which has recently been released contains a second longitudinal measurement of numerical ability and the 2010 questionnaire is scheduled to include the literacy items.
9
A similar study in the United States – the Health and Retirement Study – delivered an experimental module of measures of financial numeracy to a subsample of their survey respondents, partly with the aim of allowing a comparison to the ELSA measures, in their 2004 wave. Although the questions are not strictly comparable, a descriptive analysis of this US data and how it correlates with retirement saving arrangements is presented in Lusardi and Mitchell (2007).
10
Banks and Oldfield (2007) experimented with splitting the largest group (Group II) into two further subgroups, and their conclusions were unaffected. We do not pursue it further here.
11
Of course, cohort effects in the proportion of individuals with higher levels of education (if this extra education led to higher levels of numeracy) would affect the composition of individuals across age bands and might affect the bias in any measure of the unconditional age decline in numeracy.
12
The literacy test is a simple set of three questions relating to a short paragraph of text about a hypothetical medicine and the circumstances under which it should be taken. The paragraph is printed on a card and respondents are allowed to refer to the card whilst answering the questions. The test is scored categorically from 1 to 3 according to how many of the answers given were correct (with those giving no correct answers grouped together with those giving one correct answer).
13
All couple-level specifications have been run using individual level numeracy instead of the maximum level of numeracy in a couple in order to check whether our results are sensitive to this particular choice of specification. While there are some small differences in standard errors none of the substantive qualitative findings are affected.
14
Of course, to interpret these as true age-profiles for date of birth cohorts we would need numeracy to be constant for each date-of-birth cohort over the period in question, which is one of the reasons we choose two numeracy groups rather than four for this analysis. In addition, the profiles in Figure 3 cannot necessarily be interpreted as cohort profiles since, unlike the means presented in Figure 2, the quantiles do not necessarily refer to the same households in each year and so composition is not necessarily constant over time.
16
Individuals immediately around the time of retirement, i.e. aged 60–64 in 2002, who would be 64–68 by the end of the sample, are omitted from the analysis due to the potentially complex wealth transitions associated with receipt of lump sums from pensions that may be occurring around this time. In addition, since retirement ages vary widely within this window it is not clear whether this age sample would or should be, on average, accumulating or decumulating wealth.
17
We do not exclude the very lowest numeracy group because it is a very small group and for presentational purposes, when looking at differences between groups, any tests relative to the very bottom have very low power. Also, given the bottom group is a very low benchmark, it could be argued that this group is very different from the rest of the population.
18
Of course, one should be careful making inferences about consumption smoothing, or food consumption in particular, from data on food expenditures since, particularly around the time of retirement, individuals might change the quality or type of food consumed, perhaps switching away from pre-prepared meals and food out towards food that takes longer to prepare (see for example Aguiar and Hurst (2007).
19
Strictly speaking our measure of income is at the level of the benefit unit – which is defined as a couple with any dependent children that they have. However, given that such children tend not to have income (or wealth, which is also defined at the benefit unit level), we tend to use the term benefit unit and couple interchangeably in this paper.
20
Individuals receive questions referring to different ages according to their own age and sex. Specifically, 50–59 year old men and 55–59 year old women both receive questions about their expectation of working at age 60 whilst 60–64 year old men receive questions about age 65 and 50–54 year old women receive questions about age 55.
21
A strong correlation of low numeracy with labour market status, coupled with low prevalence of low numeracy amongst the youngest (working-age) groups means that our sample size is insufficient to do this analysis broken down by a four-way numeracy split.
22
In this section we work with individual level numeracy, literacy and cognitive function measures since expectations are characterized at the individual level. In contrast, in the previous section the outcomes which we analysed (wealth and replacement rates) were defined at the level of the couple so in defining measures of cognitive ability we used the maximum level of each measure within a couple.
23
This is a 19-item scale combining questions on Control, Autonomy, Self-realisation and Pleasure. See e.g. Netuveli et al (2006) for more details.
Contributor Information
James Banks, Institute for Fiscal Studies and University College London.
Cormac O’Dea, Institute for Fiscal Studies.
Zoë Oldfield, Institute for Fiscal Studies.
References
- Aguiar M, Hurst E. Life-cycle prices and production. American Economic Review. 2007;vol. 97:1533–1559. [Google Scholar]
- Ainslie G. The Breakdown of Will. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; 2001. [Google Scholar]
- Ameriks J, Andrew C, Leahy J. Wealth accumulation and the propensity to plan. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 2003;vol. 118:1007–1048. [Google Scholar]
- Banks J, Blundell R, Tanner S. Is there a retirement-savings puzzle? American Economic Review. 1998;vol. 88:769–788. [Google Scholar]
- Banks J, Emmerson C. Public and private pensions: principles, practice and the need for reform. Fiscal Studies. 2000;vol. 21:1–63. [Google Scholar]
- Banks J, Emmerson C, Oldfield Z, Tetlow G. Prepared for retirement? The adequacy and distribution of retirement resources in England. London: Institute for Fiscal Studies; 2005. Report no. 67. [Google Scholar]
- Banks J, Marmot M, Oldfield Z, Smith JP. Disease and disadvantage in the United States and in England. Journal of the American Medical Association. 2006;vol. 295:2037–2045. doi: 10.1001/jama.295.17.2037. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Banks J, Muriel A, Smith JP. Attrition and health in ELSA and the HRS. Longitudinal and Life Course Studies. 2010 forthcoming; doi: 10.14301/llcs.v2i2.115. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Banks J, Oldfield Z. Understanding pensions: cognitive function, numeracy and retirement saving. Fiscal Studies. 2007;vol. 28:143–170. [Google Scholar]
- Benjamin D, Brown SA, Shapiro JM. Who is Behavioral? Cognitive Ability and Anomalous Preferences. mimeo: Harvard University; 2006. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Bettinger E, Slonim R. Patience among Children: Evidence from a Field Experiment. Journal of Public Economics. 2007;vol. 91:343–363. [Google Scholar]
- Borghans L, Duckworth A, Heckman J, Weel B. The economics and psychology of personality traits. Journal of Human Resources. 2008;vol. 43:972–1059. [Google Scholar]
- Browning M, Lusardi A. Household saving: micro theories and micro facts. Journal of Economic Literature. 1996;vol. 34:1797–1855. [Google Scholar]
- Burks SV, Carpenter J, Goette L, Rustichini A. Cognitive skills affect economic preferences, strategic behavior and job attachment. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences. 2009;vol. 106(no. 19):7745–7750. doi: 10.1073/pnas.0812360106. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Bozio A, Crawford R, Tetlow G. Institute for Fiscal Studies Briefing Note No. 105. London: Institute for Fiscal Studies; 2010. The history of state pensions in the UK: 1948–2010. [Google Scholar]
- Deaton A. The Analysis of Household Surveys: A Microeconometric Approach to Development Policy. Baltimore and London: The Johns Hopkins University Press; 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Frederick S. Cognitive reflection and decision making. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2005;vol. 19:25–42. [Google Scholar]
- Gottfredson L. Intelligence: Is it the Epidemiologists elusive “fundamental cause” of social class inequalities in health?”. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology. 2004;86(1):174–199. doi: 10.1037/0022-3514.86.1.174. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Gul F, Pesendorfer W. Self-control and the theory of consumption. Econometrica. 2004;vol. 72:119–158. [Google Scholar]
- Koenker R, Hallock K. Quantile Regression. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2001;vol. 19:143–156. [Google Scholar]
- Kirby K, Winston GC, Santiesteban M. Impatience and grades: delay discount rates correlate negatively with college GPA. Learning and Individual Differences. 2005;vol. 15:213–222. [Google Scholar]
- Laibson D. Golden eggs and hyperbolic discounting. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 1997;vol. 112:443–477. [Google Scholar]
- Lusardi A, Mitchell O. Baby boomer retirement security: the roles of planning, financial literacy and housing wealth. Journal of Monetary Economics. 2007;vol. 54:205–224. [Google Scholar]
- Lusardi A. Information, expectations and savings for retirement. In: Aaron HJ, editor. Behavioural dimensions of retirement economics. Washington: Brookings Institution Press; 1999. [Google Scholar]
- Maitland S, Intrieri R, Schaie W, Willis S. Gender differences and changes in cognitive abilities across the adult life span. Aging, Neuropsychology and Cognition. 2000;vol. 7(1):32–53. [Google Scholar]
- Marmot M, Banks J, Blundell R, Lessof C, Nazroo J, editors. Health, Wealth and Lifestyles of The Older Population in England: The 2002 English Longitudinal Study of Ageing. London: Institute for Fiscal Studies; 2003. [Google Scholar]
- Melzer D, Gardener E, Guralnik J. Mobility disability in the middle-aged: cross-sectional associations in the English Longitudinal Study of Ageing. Age and Ageing. 2005;vol. 34:594–602. doi: 10.1093/ageing/afi188. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Netuveli G, Wiggins R, Hildon Z, Montgomery S, Blane D. Functional limitation in long standing illness and quality of life: evidence from the English Longitudinal Study of Ageing. British Medical Journal. 2006;vol. 331:1382–1383. doi: 10.1136/bmj.331.7529.1382. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Office for National Statistics. Adult Literacy in Britain. London: Office for National Statistics; 1997. [Google Scholar]
- Parker AM, Fischhoff B. Decision-making competence: external validation through an individual-differences approach. Journal of Behavioral Decision Making. 2005;vol. 18:1–27. [Google Scholar]
- Peters E, Vastfjall D, Slovie P, Mertz CK, Mazzocco K, Dickert S. Numeracy and decision making. Psychological Science. 2005;vol. 17:407–413. doi: 10.1111/j.1467-9280.2006.01720.x. [DOI] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Pickering A. A Simpler Way to Better Pensions. London: Department for Work and Pensions; 2002. [Google Scholar]
- Sandler R. Medium and Long Term Retail Savings in the UK. London: The Stationery Office; 2002. [Google Scholar]
- Schaie K. Intellectual development in adulthood. In: Birren J, Schaie K, editors. Handbook of the Psychology of Aging. 4th edition. San Diego: Academic Press; 1996. pp. 266–286. [Google Scholar]
- Schaie K, Willis S, Caskie G. The Seattle longitudinal study: relationship between personality and cognition. Aging, Neuropsychology, and Cognition. 2004;vol. 11:304–324. doi: 10.1080/13825580490511134. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Shiv B, Fedorikhin A. Heart and mind in conflict: the interplay of affect and cognition in consumer decision making. Journal of Consumer Research. 1999;vol. 26:72–89. [Google Scholar]
- Smith JP, Willis R, McArdle JJ. Financial decision making and cognition in a family context. ECONOMIC JOURNAL. 2010 doi: 10.1111/j.1468-0297.2010.02394.x. this issue. [DOI] [PMC free article] [PubMed] [Google Scholar]
- Steel N, Huppert F, McWilliams B, Melzer D. Physical and cognitive function. In: Marmot M, Banks J, Blundell R, Lessof C, Nazroo J, editors. Health, wealth and lifestyles of the older population in England: The 2002 English Longitudinal Study of Ageing. London: Institute for Fiscal Studies; 2003. [Google Scholar]